Property.
7.—Collectivism. The Facts Speak
[Continued.]
The manner in which industrial corporations and political rings
own American city governments for their own emolument at the cost of the public
requires no enlargement here. Like the brigands and pirates of former times they
swoop down upon the unwitting and defenceless people, not with pistol and
dagger, but by the more insidious and no less dangerous methods of political
manipulation and legal imposition in the guise of majority rule. They
contaminate everything they touch; incapacity marks every act, dishonesty all
their dealings. No city, large or small, escapes. Philadelphia has its
gas ring and jobbery in all departments, creating a state of chronic scandal;
New York its boodlers and Tammany rings; Chicago, perpetual
corruption and rascality in its government and administration; Boston has
its West End Railroad Company, which not only makes puppets of those in power
and buys the silence of the press, but is commonly said to have in its pay the
whole State legislature. Every city presents no less conclusive testimony.
Mr. Joseph Chamberlain recently proved in the Forum that the best governed (?) city in the States,
Boston, requires five times as much money to run the government as a city
of equal size, Birmingham, in England, and at the same time fails to give
anywhere near as much return in efficiency and services to the citizens. Yet
English municipal organizations are no less open to objection, either on
principle or on practical achievement, than their American counterparts. Before
the advocates of municipalization
and nationalization
can make out
a claim for serious attention to their schemes, they must furnish evidence to
rebut the almost overwhelming testimony which demonstrates the utter failure,
moral and industrial, of all existing manifestations of practical authoritative
Socialism. In default, their demands are unworthy of notice and their proposed
reforms abortive. It is not, however, the theories of these schools alone which
have to be disproved; the principles they uphold have entered largely into
practical politics, and there exists a body of opinion, to all appearance on the
increase, which sees nothing but good for the people in the indefinite expansion
of the principle of compulsory collectivism. Thus we may observe continuous
efforts to show that every time a new function is assumed by the authorities, as
the supplying of light in cities, a cheapening of the commodity to the people is
effected. Prices of the municipal product are compared with those of private
companies, and sometimes the latter are shown to be higher. But it is nearly
always forgotten that private corporations carrying on such operations do so in
accordance with franchises obtained from the authorities which choke off
competition and virtually create the closest of monopolies. Where exclusive
rights exist, the benefits of free industry need not be looked for; the choice
in such cases lies between a private and a public monopoly, either of which is a
direct infringement on individual liberty and clearly unjust.
An erroneous assumption underlies this desire for enlarging public or common property and organization of labor. It is assumed that the profits accruing to private enterprise, to the capitalists, out of business which might be run socialistically, would in the latter circumstance go directly into the collectivist treasury and be used for the general good. Of what do such profits consist? Chiefly interest; yet the collectivists are willing that the authorities take over these functions and pay interest for the necessary capital. True, they imagine that interest would speedily be abolished by some legal enactment or popular plebiscite. But no sound conception of economic principles will admit the efficacy of such methods. Nevertheless, this desire is a tacit admission that the elimination of interest is an essential feature of economic reform, while it must always be insisted that no merely political method can permanently secure this desirable result.
The other factors usually included in profits arising either out
of risk, superior facilities, or skill in management could not by any
possibility be transferred to the collective authority. With the substitution of
industrial Socialism for voluntary enterprise they would simply cease to exist.
The source which created them being destroyed, society would be just so much the
poorer. And the evidence is against the belief that collectivism would enrich
the community, by its ability to manage and administer property and enterprise,
beyond what competitive effort has proved itself capable of doing. In short, the
advocates of the collectivist movement overlook the fact that the earnings of
industrial enterprise above the current rate of interest are properly returns
for services rendered, and should not be confounded with the unearned
increment
of either interest or rent. An exception to this must be
mentioned. In the case of a monopoly a tax may be exacted which, though called
profit, is neither interest nor payment for services, but simply an unjust abuse
of power. The United States government, when its shuts
out all competitors and charges a rate for letters beyond the cost of that
branch of the service and uses the accruing profit to make good the deficit
caused by its unsound management of the newspaper and periodical branch, is a
pertinent example. We could add also the English post-office and telegraph
service, upon which the government raises a large income in the name of profits,
but which is truly a tax on the people, and the English municipal authorities,
who realize big profits on the gas monopoly which they use in
improvements,
whose principal effects are to enhance the value of real
estate and increase rents. Unofficial capitalistic monopolies by legislative aid
not infrequently do the same thing.
Therefore the one possible benefit which collectivism might be expected to accomplish,—namely, the saving to the producers of that portion of profits which is interest proper,—it offers no promise of effecting. And it has just been shown that the remaining portions would not be saved. Hence we arrive at the conclusion that the claim made on behalf of Socialism to return to the producers the profits now received by the capitalist class without foundation. The analysis in this chapter harmonizes with the preceding by showing that collective ownership of property and compulsory industrial organization offer no advantages over private property and capitalism. So that, judging only by expediency, by the observed results and the possible benefits, collectivism as a solution of the social problem cannot be entertained.